Key Takeaway:

The concept of “nudge theory” has gained prominence 15 years after its 2008 book, “Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness.” The book, which inspired politicians like Barack Obama and David Cameron, led to the creation of government teams to incorporate nudge theory into public policy. However, the success of these nudges is not universally agreed upon. Critics argue that nudges have small effects on behavior and are ineffective policy tools, as they may be used by vested interests to distract policymakers and the public from more effective solutions. Despite this, nudge theory remains useful in the political sphere as cheap solutions to difficult problems are cheaper and less controversial. This suggests that nudges may continue to have a role in modern society, as politicians will always demand a tool like them for their political ends.


Itโ€™s been 15 years since a particular concept of behavioural science went mainstream. โ€œNudge theoryโ€, the notion that our behaviour can be successfully influenced through โ€œsoftโ€ interventions, has subsequently appealed to plenty of people seeking to change the way we live.ย 

The 2008 book which set out the idea โ€“ Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness โ€“ sold more than 2 million copies. But its influence went way beyond sales figures. 

The authors โ€“ behavioural economist Richard Thaler and law professor Cass Sunstein โ€“ inspired powerful politicians, including former US president Barack Obama and former UK prime minister David Cameron to set up government teams with the specific remit of incorporating nudge theory into public policy. 

These โ€œnudge unitsโ€ became widespread, with recent research suggesting there are now overย 200 of themย around the world. But while teams of policymakers appear happy to have been taking their โ€œnudge-pillsโ€, making small changes to our decision-making processes, the success of those carefully designed nudges is by no means universally agreed.ย 

Back in 2008 though, whether or not nudges actually worked was rarely discussed. The book was packed with peer-reviewed studies, and set out an idea that was broad enough for many readers to relate to. It felt intuitive. 

Instead, criticism of nudging at the time typically focused on concerns that government nudges undermined individual freedom. The worry was that if nudges could lead to major changes in personal decision-making and be used to influence citizen behaviour, then this created the risk of illegitimate state overreach โ€“ maybe even totalitarianism.

These days, while some questions remain about individual freedom, they are not as prominent. One reason appears to be a general acceptance that some government influence on citizens and the decisions they make is surely inevitable. But there is also the fact that a large amount of evidence questions whether nudges actually work at all. 

After 15 years, plenty of nudge studies can now be assessed to get a better sense of whether this seemingly revolutionary idea really delivers. Behavioural economists undertake this assessment using an approach called โ€œmeta-analysisโ€, which combines multiple studies to get the most reliable data. Last year, one major meta-analysis reported finding no evidence of nudges working. 

This was a big deal. And although the study had its own critics, who say it does not properly account for context, the analysis also supported previous evidence of publication bias, suggesting researchers have been cherry picking the โ€œgoodโ€ nudge studies to publish for years. 

Nudge theory has also been undermined elsewhere by doubts raised around the usefulness of findings in behavioural science and psychology, as well as high-profile scandals involving allegations of data fabrication

Pushing back against nudging

Critics of nudge theory have two key arguments. One is the notion that nudges have small (if any) effects on our behaviour, and are therefore ineffective policy tools

Their second point is that nudge-based acts are open to being used by vested interests to distract policymakers and the public from actually effective solutions โ€“ that they put the emphasis on slight changes from individuals instead of more meaningful and effective systemic change.

For instance, nudges that encourage households to reduce their energy consumption may be considered a good idea. But what if this nudge also reduces the political will to pursue more effective (and expensive) policies, such as retrofitting homes or dramatically investing in sources of sustainable energy?

Even supporters of nudge theory have conceded that nudges may have overpromised in the past. A recent behavioural science โ€œmanifestoโ€ argues that behavioural economists should โ€œbe humbleโ€ about limits of nudge theory. And in a 2021 updated edition of their famous book, Thaler and Sunstein โ€“ who never anticipated the phenomenal reach they achieved โ€“ argue that nudges are always part of the solution, but rarely the solution itself

Barack Obama
Nudge, nudge. Evan El-Amin/Shutterstock

In the political sphere though, nudge theory will probably continue to prosper, as a way of gaining political capital from cheap solutions to difficult problems. For instance, the nudge of automatically enrolling UK workers into pension schemes (they have the right to opt out) has substantially increased the number of people saving for retirement, an ambition of both Labour and Conservative governments. 

This policy uses a common type of nudge known as a โ€œdefault optionโ€, which relies on peopleโ€™s tendency to accept the status quo. Before automatic enrolment, employers were still obliged to provide a pension scheme, but employees had to request access to it. 

But even when nudged in this soft, almost passive way, people probably arenโ€™t saving enough โ€“ mainly because they canโ€™t afford to. Fundamental pension reform or a radical change to wealth distribution is politically challenging and expensive, whereas nudging workers into passive enrolment is not.

Nudges are also less controversial to the electorate than a new ban or mandate. A gentle push towards more environmentally friendly behaviour is likely to provoke less backlash among voters than a government ordering people to change the way they do things.

In this sense then, nudges remain useful political tools. They are cheap, and they neither ban nor mandate. And if they donโ€™t work, it takes a while for voters to notice. 

So perhaps nudges do not even need to work to continue to have a role in modern society, because politicians will always demand a tool like them for their political ends. It is an argument that could nudge nudging along for at least another 15 years.

Contributor

Recently Published

Key Takeaway: Jonathan Haidt’s book, The Anxious Generation, calls for action to limit teenagers’ smartphone access and address the mental health crisis caused by the widespread use of smartphones. Haidt cites the “great rewiring” period from 2010 to 2015 as a time when adolescents’ neural systems were primed for anxiety and depression by daily smartphone […]

Top Picks

Key Takeaway: A study has found that humble leaders can become more promotable by growing others through a “humility route”. Human capital theory suggests that employees’ value can be enhanced by investing in their knowledge, skills, and abilities. Humble leaders focus on the learning and growth of their followers, creating human capital value for themselves. […]
Key Takeaway: Leading scientists and technologists often make terrible predictions about the direction of innovation, leading to misalignments between a company’s economic incentives to profit from its proprietary AI model and society’s interests in how the AI model should be monetised and deployed. Focusing on the economic risks from AI is not just about preventing […]

Trending

I highly recommend reading the McKinsey Global Instituteโ€™s new report, โ€œReskilling China: Transforming The Worldโ€™s Largest Workforce Into Lifelong Learnersโ€, which focuses on the countryโ€™s biggest employment challenge, re-training its workforce and the adoption of practices such as lifelong learning to address the growing digital transformation of its productive fabric. How to transform the country […]

Join our Newsletter

Get our monthly recap with the latest news, articles and resources.

Login

Welcome to Empirics

We are glad you have decided to join our mission of gathering the collective knowledge of Asia!
Join Empirics